Araştırma Makalesi
BibTex RIS Kaynak Göster

Innovation in The European Union Within The Framework of The Theory of Creative Destruction: An Overview After The Global Financial Crisis 2008

Yıl 2020, Cilt: 5 Sayı: 3, 682 - 705, 31.12.2020
https://doi.org/10.30784/epfad.822774

Öz

Innovations are vital for economic development. Schumpeter, the famous economic theorist who drew attention to the innovation activities, was the first to reveal that capitalism has a structure that realizes development through innovations. Along with the 2000s, the European Union adopted a Schumpeterian approach and launched the Lisbon Strategy, however, this strategy has not been successful for various reasons. In this context, the Schumpeterian theory of “creative destruction” is well suited for evaluating innovation activities in the European Union. The main purpose of the study is to analyze the innovation activities in the European Union through research and development expenditures, business research and development expenditures, and the numbers of patent applications in the context of the theory of “creative destruction” put forward by Schumpeter. In this context, it was tried to reveal the Schumpeterian innovation capacity of the European Union between 2008 and 2018 in line with the data obtained from Eurostat. As a result of the study, it was concluded that innovation activities in the European Union could not fully realize the creative destruction effect and that there is a serious texture incompatibility in terms of economic structures within the EU member countries.

Destekleyen Kurum

This study was funded by Scientific Research Projects Coordination Unit of Istanbul University. Project number: 47855

Proje Numarası

47855

Kaynakça

  • Acs, Z. J. and Audretsch, D. B. (2010). Handbook of entrepreneurship research an interdisciplinary survey and introduction (2. Ed.). New York: Springer.
  • Aghion, P. (2008). Schumpeterian growth and growth policy design. In S. Durlauf and L. E. Blume (Eds.), Economic growth the new palgrave economics collection (pp. 229-236). London: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60(2), 323-351. doi:10.3386/w3223
  • Aghion, P., Akcigit, U. and Howitt, P. (2013). What do we learn from Schumpeterian growth theory? (NBER Working Paper Series No. 18824). Retrieved from https://www.nber.org/papers/w18824
  • Alada, D. (2001). İktisadi düşünce tarihinde girişimcilik kavramı üzerine notlar. İstanbul Üniversitesi Siyasal Bilgiler Fakültesi Dergisi, 0(23-24), 47-52. Retrieved from https://dergipark.org.tr/tr/pub/siyasal
  • Andersen, E. S. (2002). Railroadization as Schumpeter’s standard sase: An evolutionary-ecological account. Industry and Innovation, 9(1-2), 41-78. https://doi.org/10.1080/13662710220123617
  • Andersen, E. S., Dahl, M. S., Lundvall, B.-A. and Reichstein, T. (2006). Schumpeter’s process of creative destruction and the scandinavian systems: a tale of two effects. Paper presented at the DRUID Conference on Knowledge, Innovation and Competitiveness. Copenhagen, Denmark. Retrieved from https://vbn.aau.dk/en/publications/schumpeter39s-process-of-creative-destruction-and-thescandinavia
  • Braunnerhjelm, P. and Svensson, R. (2007). The inventor’s role: was Schumpeter right? (Working Paper Series in Economics and Institutions of Innovation No. 78). Retrieved from https://econpapers.repec.org/paper/hhscesisp/0078.htm
  • Cipolla, C. M. (2005). Before the industrial revolution European society and economy 1000-1700 (3. Ed.). New York: Routledge.
  • Corriveau, L. (1994). Entrepreneurs, growth and cycles. Economica, 61(241), 1-15. doi:10.2307/2555046
  • Ebner, A. (2000 June-July). Schumpeterian theory and the sources of economic development: endogenous, evolutionary or entrepreneurial? Paper presented at the International Schumpeter Society Conference on ‘Change Development and Transformation: Transdisciplinary Perspectives on the Innovation Process’. Manchester, United Kingdom
  • Erixon, F. (2010). The Europe 2020 strategy: time for Europe to think again. European View, 9(1), 29- 37. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12290-010-0120-8
  • European Commission (2010a). Lisbon strategy for growth and jobs. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/archives/growthandjobs_2009/
  • European Commission. (2010b). Communication from the commission Europe 2020. Retrieved from https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52010DC2020&from=en
  • European Commission. (2010c). Commission staff working document lisbon strategy evaluation document. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/archives/growthandjobs_2009/pdf/lisbon_strategy_evaluation_en.pdf
  • Eurostat (2013). Glossary: Lisbon strategy. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statisticsexplained/index.php/Glossary:Lisbon_Strategy
  • Eurostat. (2020a). Europe 2020 overwiev. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/europe-2020- indicators#:~:text=The%20Europe%202020%20strategy%20is,a%20sustainable%20social%20
  • Eurostat. (2020b) Gross domestic expenditure on R&D (GERD) [Dataset]. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/databrowser/view/t2020_20/default/table?lang=en
  • Eurostat. (2020c). Europe 2020 headline indicators. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statisticsexplained/index.php/Europe_2020_headline_indicators#Gross_domestic_expenditure_on_resear ch_and_development_.28R.26D.29
  • Eurostat. (2020d). Business expenditure on r&d (BERD) by NACE Rev. 2 activity [Dataset]. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/databrowser/view/rd_e_berdindr2/default/table?lang=en
  • Eurostat. (2020e). Patent applications to the european patent office [Dataset]. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/databrowser/view/sdg_09_40/default/table?lang=en
  • Fabricant, S. (1954). Economic progress and economic change (NBER Annual Report No. 34). Retrieved from https://www.nber.org/books-and-chapters/economic-progress-and-economicchange/economic-progress-and-economic-change
  • Foders, F. and Vogelsang, M. M. (2014). Why is Germany’s manufacturing industry so competitive (Kiel Policy Brief No. 69). Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/zbw/ifwkpb/69.html
  • Godin, B. (2008). In the shadow of Schumpeter: W. Rupert Maclaurin and the study of technological innovation. Minerva, 46, 343-360. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11024-008-9100-4
  • Griliches, Z. (1990). Patent statistics as economic indicators: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 28(4), 1661-1707. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org/
  • Günar, A. (2017). Past failure, new future: An analysis of the European Union development strategiesfrom Lisbon to Europe 2020. In M. Khosrow-Pour (Eds.), Handbook of research on global enterprise operations and opportunities (pp. 244-264). USA: IGI Global
  • Hagedoorn, J. (1996). Innovation and entrepreneurship: Schumpeter revisited. Industrial and Corporate Change, 5(3), 883-896. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/5.3.883
  • Hart, S. L. and Milstein, M. B. (1999). Global sustainability and the creative destruction of industries. MIT Sloan Management Review, 41(1), 23-33. Retrieved from https://go.gale.com/
  • Hartshorn, J., Micheal, M., Crooks, J., Stahl, R. and Bond, Z. (2005). Creative destruction: building toward sustainability. Canada Journal of Civil Engineering, 32(1), 170-180. https://doi.org/10.1139/l04-119
  • Harvey, D. (2010). The enigma of capital and the crises of capitalism. United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.
  • Hébert, R. F. and Link, A. N. (1989). In search of the meaning of entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 1(1), 39-49. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00389915
  • Kirzner, I. M. (1999). Creativity and/or alertness: a reconsideration of the Schumpeterain entrepreneur. Review of Austrian Economics, 11, 5-17. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1007719905868
  • Kuznets, S. (1940). Schumpeter’s business cycles. The American Economic Review, 30(2), 257-271. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org/
  • Ledeen, M. (2007). The war against the terror masters: Why it happened where we are now how we’ll win. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
  • Masfield, E. (1972). Contribution of R&D to economic growth in the united states. Sciences, 175(4021), 477-486. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org/
  • Merriam-Webster. (2020). Innovation. Retrieved from https://www.merriam webster.com/dictionary/innovation
  • Moloi, T. and Marvala, T. (2020). Artificial intelligence in economics and finance theories. Switzerland: Springer.
  • Moran, N. (2006). Patents are engine of economic growth, says wipo. Sciens Business. Retrieved from https://sciencebusiness.net/news/73133/Patents-are-engine-of-economic-growth%2C-saysWIPO#:~:text=The%20number%20of%20patent%20applications,of%20some%205.6%20per%2 0cent market%20economy.
  • Nadiri, M. I. (1993). Innovations and technological spillovers (NBER Working Paper No. w4423). Retrieved from https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=227322
  • Natali, D. (2010). The Lisbon strategy europe 2020 and the crisis in between (European Social Observatory Deliverable No. 4). Retrieved from http://www.ose.be/files/publication/2010/Natali_2010_Lisbon%20StrategyEU2020&Crisis.pdf
  • Page, M. (2001). Creative destruction of manhattan 1900-1940. United States of America: University of Chicago Press.
  • Reinert, E. S. (2006). European integration innovation and uneven economic growth: challenges and problems of EU 2005 (The Other Canon Foundation and Tallinn University of Technology Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics No. 05). Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/tth/wpaper/05.html
  • Reinert, E. S. (2013). Primitivization of the EU periphery: the loss of relevant knowledge. (The Other Canon Foundation and Tallinn University of Technology Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics No. 48). Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/tth/wpaper/48.html
  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1939). Business cycles a theoretical, historical, and statistical of the capitalist process (vol. 1). United States of America: McGraw-Hill Book Company.
  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1947). The creative response in economic history. The Journal of Economic History, 7(2), 149-159. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org
  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1951). Theory of economic development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
  • Schumpeter, J. A. (2006). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Routledge.
  • Segerstrom, P. S., Anant, T. C. A. and Dinopoulos, E. (1990). A Schumpeterian model of product life cycle. The American Economic Review, 80(5), 1077-1091. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org/
  • Solow, R. M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(3), 312-320. doi:10.2307/1926047
  • Swedberg, R. (2006). Social entrepreneurship: The view of the young Schumpeter. In C. Steyaert and D. Hjort (Eds.), Entrepreneurship as social change a third movements in entrepreneurship book (pp. 21-34). UK: Edward Elgar.
  • Sweezy, P. M. (1943). Professor Schumpeter’s theory of innovation. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 25(1), 93-96. doi:10.2307/1924551
  • Temin, P. (2002). The golden age of European growth reconsidered. Europan Review of Economic History, 6(1), 3-22. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org/
  • Thurik, R. and Wennekers, S. (2004). Entrepreneurship, small business and economic growth. Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development, 11(1), 140-149. https://doi.org/10.1108/14626000410519173
  • Wong, P. K., Ho, Y. P. and Autio, E. (2005). Entrepreneurship, innovation and economic growth: Evidence from GEM data. Small Business Economics, 24, 335-350. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-005-2000-1
  • World Intellectual Property Organization. (2019). The geography of innovation: local hotspots, global networks. Retrieved from https://www.wipo.int/edocs/pubdocs/en/wipo_pub_944_2019.pdf

Yaratıcı Yıkım Teorisi Çerçevesinde Avrupa Birliği’nde Yenilik: 2008 Küresel Krizi Sonrasına Bir Bakış

Yıl 2020, Cilt: 5 Sayı: 3, 682 - 705, 31.12.2020
https://doi.org/10.30784/epfad.822774

Öz

Ekonomik gelişme için yenilikler hayati önem taşımaktadır. Yenilik faaliyetlerine ünlü iktisat düşünürü Schumpeter dikkati çekerek, kapitalizmin yenilikler yolu ile kalkınmayı gerçekleştiren bir yapıya sahip olduğunu ortaya koyan ilk düşünür olmuştur. 2000’li yıllar ile birlikte Avrupa Birliği Schumpeteryan bir yaklaşım benimseyerek Lizbon stratejisini kabul etmiş, ancak strateji çeşitli nedenlerle başarılı olamamıştır. Bu bağlamda Schumpeteryan “yaratıcı yıkım” teorisi Avrupa Birliği’nde yenilik faaliyetlerini değerlendirmek için oldukça uygundur. Çalışmanın temel amacı; Schumpeter tarafından ortaya konulan “yaratıcı yıkım” teorisi bağlamında Avrupa Birliği’ndeki yenilik faaliyetlerinin, araştırma ve geliştirme harcamaları, işletme araştırma ve geliştirme harcamaları ve patent başvuru sayıları ile analiz edilmesidir. Bu bağlamda Eurostat’tan elde edilen veriler doğrultusunda 2008 ile 2018 yılları arasında Avrupa Birliği’nin Schumpeteryan yenilik kapasitesinin gösterilmesine gayret edilmiştir. Çalışma sonucunda Avrupa Birliği’nde yenilik faaliyetlerinin yaratıcı yıkım etkisini tam olarak gerçekleştiremediği ve AB üyesi ülkelerde iktisadi yapılar bakımından ciddi bir doku uyuşmazlığı olduğu sonucuna varılmıştır.

Proje Numarası

47855

Kaynakça

  • Acs, Z. J. and Audretsch, D. B. (2010). Handbook of entrepreneurship research an interdisciplinary survey and introduction (2. Ed.). New York: Springer.
  • Aghion, P. (2008). Schumpeterian growth and growth policy design. In S. Durlauf and L. E. Blume (Eds.), Economic growth the new palgrave economics collection (pp. 229-236). London: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60(2), 323-351. doi:10.3386/w3223
  • Aghion, P., Akcigit, U. and Howitt, P. (2013). What do we learn from Schumpeterian growth theory? (NBER Working Paper Series No. 18824). Retrieved from https://www.nber.org/papers/w18824
  • Alada, D. (2001). İktisadi düşünce tarihinde girişimcilik kavramı üzerine notlar. İstanbul Üniversitesi Siyasal Bilgiler Fakültesi Dergisi, 0(23-24), 47-52. Retrieved from https://dergipark.org.tr/tr/pub/siyasal
  • Andersen, E. S. (2002). Railroadization as Schumpeter’s standard sase: An evolutionary-ecological account. Industry and Innovation, 9(1-2), 41-78. https://doi.org/10.1080/13662710220123617
  • Andersen, E. S., Dahl, M. S., Lundvall, B.-A. and Reichstein, T. (2006). Schumpeter’s process of creative destruction and the scandinavian systems: a tale of two effects. Paper presented at the DRUID Conference on Knowledge, Innovation and Competitiveness. Copenhagen, Denmark. Retrieved from https://vbn.aau.dk/en/publications/schumpeter39s-process-of-creative-destruction-and-thescandinavia
  • Braunnerhjelm, P. and Svensson, R. (2007). The inventor’s role: was Schumpeter right? (Working Paper Series in Economics and Institutions of Innovation No. 78). Retrieved from https://econpapers.repec.org/paper/hhscesisp/0078.htm
  • Cipolla, C. M. (2005). Before the industrial revolution European society and economy 1000-1700 (3. Ed.). New York: Routledge.
  • Corriveau, L. (1994). Entrepreneurs, growth and cycles. Economica, 61(241), 1-15. doi:10.2307/2555046
  • Ebner, A. (2000 June-July). Schumpeterian theory and the sources of economic development: endogenous, evolutionary or entrepreneurial? Paper presented at the International Schumpeter Society Conference on ‘Change Development and Transformation: Transdisciplinary Perspectives on the Innovation Process’. Manchester, United Kingdom
  • Erixon, F. (2010). The Europe 2020 strategy: time for Europe to think again. European View, 9(1), 29- 37. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12290-010-0120-8
  • European Commission (2010a). Lisbon strategy for growth and jobs. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/archives/growthandjobs_2009/
  • European Commission. (2010b). Communication from the commission Europe 2020. Retrieved from https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52010DC2020&from=en
  • European Commission. (2010c). Commission staff working document lisbon strategy evaluation document. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/archives/growthandjobs_2009/pdf/lisbon_strategy_evaluation_en.pdf
  • Eurostat (2013). Glossary: Lisbon strategy. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statisticsexplained/index.php/Glossary:Lisbon_Strategy
  • Eurostat. (2020a). Europe 2020 overwiev. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/europe-2020- indicators#:~:text=The%20Europe%202020%20strategy%20is,a%20sustainable%20social%20
  • Eurostat. (2020b) Gross domestic expenditure on R&D (GERD) [Dataset]. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/databrowser/view/t2020_20/default/table?lang=en
  • Eurostat. (2020c). Europe 2020 headline indicators. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statisticsexplained/index.php/Europe_2020_headline_indicators#Gross_domestic_expenditure_on_resear ch_and_development_.28R.26D.29
  • Eurostat. (2020d). Business expenditure on r&d (BERD) by NACE Rev. 2 activity [Dataset]. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/databrowser/view/rd_e_berdindr2/default/table?lang=en
  • Eurostat. (2020e). Patent applications to the european patent office [Dataset]. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/databrowser/view/sdg_09_40/default/table?lang=en
  • Fabricant, S. (1954). Economic progress and economic change (NBER Annual Report No. 34). Retrieved from https://www.nber.org/books-and-chapters/economic-progress-and-economicchange/economic-progress-and-economic-change
  • Foders, F. and Vogelsang, M. M. (2014). Why is Germany’s manufacturing industry so competitive (Kiel Policy Brief No. 69). Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/zbw/ifwkpb/69.html
  • Godin, B. (2008). In the shadow of Schumpeter: W. Rupert Maclaurin and the study of technological innovation. Minerva, 46, 343-360. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11024-008-9100-4
  • Griliches, Z. (1990). Patent statistics as economic indicators: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 28(4), 1661-1707. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org/
  • Günar, A. (2017). Past failure, new future: An analysis of the European Union development strategiesfrom Lisbon to Europe 2020. In M. Khosrow-Pour (Eds.), Handbook of research on global enterprise operations and opportunities (pp. 244-264). USA: IGI Global
  • Hagedoorn, J. (1996). Innovation and entrepreneurship: Schumpeter revisited. Industrial and Corporate Change, 5(3), 883-896. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/5.3.883
  • Hart, S. L. and Milstein, M. B. (1999). Global sustainability and the creative destruction of industries. MIT Sloan Management Review, 41(1), 23-33. Retrieved from https://go.gale.com/
  • Hartshorn, J., Micheal, M., Crooks, J., Stahl, R. and Bond, Z. (2005). Creative destruction: building toward sustainability. Canada Journal of Civil Engineering, 32(1), 170-180. https://doi.org/10.1139/l04-119
  • Harvey, D. (2010). The enigma of capital and the crises of capitalism. United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.
  • Hébert, R. F. and Link, A. N. (1989). In search of the meaning of entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 1(1), 39-49. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00389915
  • Kirzner, I. M. (1999). Creativity and/or alertness: a reconsideration of the Schumpeterain entrepreneur. Review of Austrian Economics, 11, 5-17. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1007719905868
  • Kuznets, S. (1940). Schumpeter’s business cycles. The American Economic Review, 30(2), 257-271. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org/
  • Ledeen, M. (2007). The war against the terror masters: Why it happened where we are now how we’ll win. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
  • Masfield, E. (1972). Contribution of R&D to economic growth in the united states. Sciences, 175(4021), 477-486. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org/
  • Merriam-Webster. (2020). Innovation. Retrieved from https://www.merriam webster.com/dictionary/innovation
  • Moloi, T. and Marvala, T. (2020). Artificial intelligence in economics and finance theories. Switzerland: Springer.
  • Moran, N. (2006). Patents are engine of economic growth, says wipo. Sciens Business. Retrieved from https://sciencebusiness.net/news/73133/Patents-are-engine-of-economic-growth%2C-saysWIPO#:~:text=The%20number%20of%20patent%20applications,of%20some%205.6%20per%2 0cent market%20economy.
  • Nadiri, M. I. (1993). Innovations and technological spillovers (NBER Working Paper No. w4423). Retrieved from https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=227322
  • Natali, D. (2010). The Lisbon strategy europe 2020 and the crisis in between (European Social Observatory Deliverable No. 4). Retrieved from http://www.ose.be/files/publication/2010/Natali_2010_Lisbon%20StrategyEU2020&Crisis.pdf
  • Page, M. (2001). Creative destruction of manhattan 1900-1940. United States of America: University of Chicago Press.
  • Reinert, E. S. (2006). European integration innovation and uneven economic growth: challenges and problems of EU 2005 (The Other Canon Foundation and Tallinn University of Technology Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics No. 05). Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/tth/wpaper/05.html
  • Reinert, E. S. (2013). Primitivization of the EU periphery: the loss of relevant knowledge. (The Other Canon Foundation and Tallinn University of Technology Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics No. 48). Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/tth/wpaper/48.html
  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1939). Business cycles a theoretical, historical, and statistical of the capitalist process (vol. 1). United States of America: McGraw-Hill Book Company.
  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1947). The creative response in economic history. The Journal of Economic History, 7(2), 149-159. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org
  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1951). Theory of economic development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
  • Schumpeter, J. A. (2006). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Routledge.
  • Segerstrom, P. S., Anant, T. C. A. and Dinopoulos, E. (1990). A Schumpeterian model of product life cycle. The American Economic Review, 80(5), 1077-1091. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org/
  • Solow, R. M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(3), 312-320. doi:10.2307/1926047
  • Swedberg, R. (2006). Social entrepreneurship: The view of the young Schumpeter. In C. Steyaert and D. Hjort (Eds.), Entrepreneurship as social change a third movements in entrepreneurship book (pp. 21-34). UK: Edward Elgar.
  • Sweezy, P. M. (1943). Professor Schumpeter’s theory of innovation. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 25(1), 93-96. doi:10.2307/1924551
  • Temin, P. (2002). The golden age of European growth reconsidered. Europan Review of Economic History, 6(1), 3-22. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org/
  • Thurik, R. and Wennekers, S. (2004). Entrepreneurship, small business and economic growth. Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development, 11(1), 140-149. https://doi.org/10.1108/14626000410519173
  • Wong, P. K., Ho, Y. P. and Autio, E. (2005). Entrepreneurship, innovation and economic growth: Evidence from GEM data. Small Business Economics, 24, 335-350. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-005-2000-1
  • World Intellectual Property Organization. (2019). The geography of innovation: local hotspots, global networks. Retrieved from https://www.wipo.int/edocs/pubdocs/en/wipo_pub_944_2019.pdf
Toplam 55 adet kaynakça vardır.

Ayrıntılar

Birincil Dil İngilizce
Konular Ekonomi
Bölüm Makaleler
Yazarlar

Altuğ Günar 0000-0001-8094-624X

Seyhun Doğan 0000-0003-3450-0612

Proje Numarası 47855
Yayımlanma Tarihi 31 Aralık 2020
Kabul Tarihi 11 Aralık 2020
Yayımlandığı Sayı Yıl 2020 Cilt: 5 Sayı: 3

Kaynak Göster

APA Günar, A., & Doğan, S. (2020). Innovation in The European Union Within The Framework of The Theory of Creative Destruction: An Overview After The Global Financial Crisis 2008. Ekonomi Politika Ve Finans Araştırmaları Dergisi, 5(3), 682-705. https://doi.org/10.30784/epfad.822774